How Evolutionary Game Theory Informs Genetics
- Alper KARAGÖL
- Feb 10, 2024
- 2 min read
Evolutionary game theory (EGT) isn't just about understanding animal behavior; it can also shed light on genes and mutations.

Understanding Polymorphism: Nature thrives on diversity, and populations often harbor individuals with different genetic makeup. EGT helps us understand why some variation persists. Many important traits, like disease resistance or crop yield, are influenced by multiple genes interacting with the environment. EGT offers tools like quantitative trait loci (QTL) mapping to identify regions of the genome associated with these traits. As genetic technologies advance, EGT is adapting too. New models incorporate complex genetic architectures, gene-environment interactions, and even spatial dynamics. For example, researchers can simulate how mutations spread through geographically structured populations, providing insights into the evolution of pathogens or invasive species.
A Bit of History:
The seeds of EGT were sown in the 1930s by Ronald Fisher, who envisioned natural selection as a "game" against the environment. However, it wasn't until the 1970s that John Maynard Smith and George R. Price truly harmonized these ideas. Their seminal work, "Evolutionary Theory of Games," laid the foundation for EGT, demonstrating its applicability to animal behavior.
EGT operates with a mathematical toolbox rich with key instruments:
Payoff matrices: These tables capture the "fitness" or "reward" each individual receives based on their strategy and the strategy of their opponent(s). Imagine a hawk-dove game, where a "hawk" strategy might give higher payoff if unchallenged but lower if met with another hawk, while a "dove" strategy yields lower but safer payoffs.
Replicator dynamics: This equation, like a dynamic conductor, dictates how the population frequencies of different strategies change based on their relative success. Strategies with higher payoffs "replicate" more, leading to their gradual dominance in the population.
Evolutionarily stable strategies (ESS): These are the "winning melodies" of evolution, strategies that, once established, resist invasion by alternative strategies. Identifying ESS helps us understand why certain behaviors persist in nature.
Extensive vs. Normal Form: Stage Variations:
Imagine a stag hunt, where cooperation yields the highest reward, but defection offers a tempting shortcut. The extensive form captures every possible interaction sequence, like a detailed score with each decision point. This is useful for complex interactions but can be cumbersome for large systems.
The normal form, like simplified sheet music, summarizes the overall payoff for each strategy. This is efficient for large populations but loses some detail. Biologists choose the form that best suits their specific evolutionary "composition."
The integration of EGT and genetics holds immense potential:
Designing personalized therapies: By incorporating individual genetic information into an EGT model, we could predict how different drugs or treatments might "play out" in their bodies, leading to more personalized medicine.
Breeding resilient crops: Simulating the evolution of pests and diseases within an EGT framework could help breed crops with resistance profiles that remain durable over time.
Understanding complex diseases: EGT models can capture the interplay between genes, environment, and immune system interactions, shedding light on the complex etiology of diseases like cancer or autoimmune disorders.
Further Read:
Ross, Don, "Game Theory", The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring 2024 Edition), Edward N. Zalta & Uri Nodelman (eds.), URL = https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2024/entries/game-theory
Comments